Inviting Participants To A Fair Marketplace
A theory of a ‘Fair Marketplace’
or a ‘Fair Price’ may be a good starting point for the creation of a Fair
Marketplace. But is it a necessary condition? Let’s explore.
Let us consider the starting
point as the presence of connected market participants (providers and consumers
of goods and services) who are willing to act in this direction and who don’t
distrust each other. There may or may not be a reason to trust, but it is
sufficient if there is no reason to distrust. Let us see if these ingredients
are sufficient to get started. There may not be a shared theory, philosophy, or
ideology. You may not understand economics at all. You may not know or agree
that the prevailing market practices are exploitative and unfair. If you say,
“I am committing to participate in a marketplace, which is based on fair
(non-exploitative) prices, not co-related with or based on the prices determined
by the existing market forces.”, we’re on.
The first step is to create a
laundry list of people with relevant details. What kind of people? Owners of
businesses, self-employed professionals or freelance service providers should
be able to participate on the supply side. On the demand side, everyone, who is
a consumer, should be able to participate. We’ve left out salaried individuals
from the supply side because they may not be in a position to influence
fairness in the operations of their employers.
One may take a stand that I want
to be fair, but I will act only when we have a fool-proof theory and everyone
all others are also fair. There is also another way to start off. We trust each
other and start off. Start-off means we begin economic exchange at prices,
which are fair and in no way compared with the price in the existing
marketplace. Let us simulate price determination and further activity leading
to an economic exchange.
Who determines the price? The
provider does. We have trusted his commitment to be fair. Can there be more
providers of the same service? Yes, there can be. Should there be a guideline
for the provider to arrive at the price? There may be a guideline, which says
that ‘The occupation/profession of the provider is expected to enable the
provider to meet his/her needs and those dependent on him/her.’
The above guideline leads us to a
very interesting scenario. There are two service providers, one a bachelor with
no dependents and leading a very minimalistic life and another, a family person
with many dependents, who require medical attention. Both provide same service.
The price that both arrive at may be vastly different. Nonetheless, both follow
the guideline. Can there be a marketplace, where different prices exist for the
same product/service?
The answer to the above question
is also interesting. We agree that the occupation/profession of the provider
should enable him to fulfil his/needs and we also agree that we trust his integrity
in arriving at the prices. Since people have different needs, the prices for
the same product or service will be different and has to be accepted. By not
accepting this difference, we will end up pushing the prices to those
determined by demand and supply. This is a completely different paradigm. It
deserves some thought.
Let’s say the new paradigm is
acceptable. In another scenario, the service provider is passionate about
photography or scuba diving or car racing. In order to meet the expenses of his
passion, he needs to jack-up the price of his service. Now is the difference in
pricing acceptable?
Before we seek an answer to the
question, let us examine the question itself. It is quite obvious that the
pricing in such a situation is not acceptable and is also unfair to the
consumer. But that is not the point. The point to be noted is that such
questions arise because we think of such a possibility. We think of such
possibilities because we’re conditioned to distrust. When we’ve trusted the
provider’s integrity to arrive at the price, we must also trust that he/she
understands that loading the expense of an expensive passion/hobby is unfair on
the consumer. Therefore, the question is redundant.
We’ve moved one more step. We’ve
accepted the new paradigm that price of a product/service may differ based on
the need of the service provider. We’ve also ruled out the possibility that the
provider will indulge in practices to hike prices, which are clearly unfair.
That leaves us with those scenarios, where there is a marginal difference of
opinion between the provider and the consumer as to ‘what is fair’. Such
differences can be and should be sorted out bilaterally.
One last point to be included in
the new paradigm (referred to earlier). As the consumer takes the
responsibility of accepting a price, which fulfills the needs of the provider,
the producer also must accept the responsibility of fulfilling that need of the
consumer, which his product is meant to satisfy. This cross acceptance of
responsibility will go a long way in determining a fair price.
Guess this may be sufficient food
for thought for one blog post. Let me continue in the next post.
Comments
Post a Comment